≡ Menu

Some Links

Pat Lynch – after reading Robert Lighthizer’s new book – accurately describes Lighthizer as “a bootlegger in a Baptist’s mask.” Two slices:

There is no point in taking any of the economic assertions in Robert Lighthizer’s new book “No Trade is Free” seriously. That would be the equivalent of a geographer taking seriously the work of a Flat Earth advocate. For many years most economists have clearly understood that free trade is hugely beneficial to both individual consumers and the economies of communities of all sizes. If Paul Krugman and Milton Friedman agree on something, it’s safe to say that it’s likely true.

…..

As taxes go, tariffs are hidden and unavoidable, which makes them dangerous to liberty and property. History is littered with trade wars that don’t end well. And even if a government could, in lieu of a tariff, offer consumers a choice to “tip” the business that produced domestically manufactured goods at a higher cost, that might be one way to handle the obvious imposition of an unfair and economically inefficient policy onto all Americans.  And if some of my fellow Americans wanted to voluntarily help their fellow citizens in the Youngstown, Ohios and Gary, Indianas of the nation, so be it. But forcing all of us, including many of us who don’t benefit from such laws, to pay the costs of maintaining these economically uncompetitive and losing industries is nothing more than a politically motivated transfer to swing voters living in competitive states. It’s pure politics motivated by the unique political institution of the Electoral College. The fact that the Biden administration has also chosen to impose high tariffs on imported goods during this election year lays bare the naked political calculation here.

Bob Lighthizer wants you to join him in what he claims is a moral crusade to save a few American jobs. He fails to mention that ultimately, we will all pay much higher costs to do this and that he, his friends and former clients, and a very narrow sliver of the nation will benefit. He is that rarest of individuals, a lawyer for a bootlegger standing at the Baptist pulpit, hoping you don’t notice who’s putting money in the collection basket on Sundays.

Colin Grabow reveals that a new protectionist bill elevates corporate interests above that of U.S. soldiers. Two slices:

Last month saw the introduction of the Better Outfitting Our Troops (BOOTS) Act, a bill that would prohibit service members from using “optional boots” manufactured outside the United States or without US materials. While presented as a means of ensuring footwear quality, the legislation appears more concerned with the welfare of US bootmakers—and one manufacturer in particular—than those in uniform.

…..

Introduced by Representatives Nikki Budzinski (D‑IL), Mike Bost (R‑IL), and Rick Crawford (R‑AR), the bill restricts optional boots to those manufactured in the United States with domestic materials and components. Although the legislation’s sponsors claim the measure seeks to promote safety, it’s unclear how reducing servicemembers’ options in selecting footwear advances that goal. Indeed, the opposite seems a more likely outcome.

So why was the bill written? A press release announcing the BOOTS Act holds some clues.

Beyond emphasizing safety, the announcement warns that foreign manufacturers have “taken over the market for Army soldier footwear” (“taking over a market” is protectionist‐​speak for providing a valued good or service at an affordable price). The BOOTS Act’s passage, it adds, would “support domestic military footwear production at places like the Belleville Shoe Manufacturing Company”—a manufacturer with facilities in or near the bill’s sponsor’s districts.

It’s difficult not to conclude that driving business to the company, one highly reliant on government contracts touted by Bost and Budzinski, is a primary motivation for the bill. Even, it seems, if that means members of the armed services are left with fewer choices in critical footwear—choices they like as evidenced by the fact that manufacturers not compliant with the BOOTS Act dominate the market.

The University of Virginia’s Steven Rhoads, writing in the Wall Street Journal, explains that lower tax rates spur investments that are good for everyone. A slice:

Politicians and the press mislead voters and readers when they claim that tax cuts for the rich don’t benefit other economic classes. We all gain from new, improved products made possible by innovative startups funded by the wealthy. Excessive taxation, doubtless a feature of a “middle-out” plan, could deplete the funds that entrepreneurs use to start and sustain useful ventures.

Americans shouldn’t worry so much about wealth distribution. Instead, we should be grateful for how the wealthy enable entrepreneurial ideas to come to life, allowing everyone to prosper.

George Will decries the U.S. Supreme Court’s recent ruling in Consumer Financial Protection Bureau v. Community Financial Services Association of America. Three slices:

Last week, “the least dangerous” branch (Alexander Hamilton’s description of the judiciary) did something dangerous. By ratifying the unprecedented structure of the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau (CFPB), the Supreme Court incentivized additional slipshod congressional work that will feed the executive branch’s sense of entitlement to unaccountable discretion in making laws and policies. The decision, which some progressives will praise as “judicial restraint,” demonstrates that this anodyne phrase often denotes a dereliction of the judicial duty to compel the other branches to act constitutionally.

…..

Last week, the court actually held, 7-2, that congressional progressives failed in their proclaimed attempt to pioneer a novel form of unaccountable autonomy for this appendage of the administrative state. Justice Clarence Thomas, joined by Chief Justice John G. Roberts Jr. and Justices Sonia Sotomayor, Elena Kagan, Brett M. Kavanaugh, Amy Coney Barrett and Ketanji Brown Jackson, said there is nothing importantly new about the CFPB’s structure. Either Thomas contradicts himself when referring to the CFPB’s various “novel structural features,” or he has unearthed a novel “original meaning” of “novel.”

The CFPB is doubly insulated from accountability through the appropriations process. The bureau funds itself by its director asserting its congressionally bestowed entitlement, in perpetuity, to up to 12 percent of the Federal Reserve’s operating expenses. These are not appropriated; they are assessments on banks and interest on the Fed’s holdings.

This, Thomas says approvingly, simply means nothing “forces” the CFPB “to regularly implore Congress” for funding. Implore? When did it become optional, even an indignity, for a federal agency to have to ask the people’s representatives for the people’s money?

…..

Justice Samuel A. Alito Jr., joined in dissent by Justice Neil M. Gorsuch, also unpacks the meaning of “appropriation” but comes to the correct conclusion that the Constitution’s framers would be “horrified” by the CFPB’s structure, which reduces the appropriations clause to “a minor vestige.” The CFPB does not even have to return unspent funds to the Treasury but can build an endowment from unspent funds. As the majority reads it, Alito writes, the appropriations clause “imposes no temporal limit that would prevent Congress from authorizing the executive to spend public funds in perpetuity.”

Also decrying the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau ruling in is Peter Wallison. A slice:

The Supreme Court has now authorized Congress to provide for the funding of agencies from sources—like the Fed—over which neither Congress nor the President has any significant control.

The reason Congress originally did this for the CFPB is clear: The Democratic Congress that created CFPB did not want the agency’s regulation of the financial system to be limited by the “politics” of a democracy; for example, some day, the regulated industry might acquire the power in Congress to reduce the authority of the CFPB.

To prevent this result, the financing of the agency was placed in the Federal Reserve, beyond the control of Congress. Although part of this independence has now been erased by Seila Law, which gave the President the power to dismiss the head of the agency in case he or she pursues policies inconsistent with those of the President.

But now a powerful agency of the government has been placed beyond the control of Congress, and by extension the American people.

Jon Miltimore is correct: So-called ‘net neutrality’ was never about saving the Internet.”

Joakim Book is no fan of Brad DeLong’s Slouching Towards Utopia. A slice:

An economic history of the 1940s, say, would involve production, government wartime dirigisme, debt financing, and postwar inflation. It would consider the faulty notion that big government wartime spending brought depressed economies out of the Great Depression of the 1930s. Instead, what DeLong delivers is a dull, textbook-type account of Britain and Germany’s warmongering. It’s the old-fashioned “maps and chaps” type of history—that aristocratic British flavor of academic investigations that look at all the wrong things (warfare, diplomatic correspondence, voting, or politicking).

Western governments of the interwar years—larger and more invasive than they had ever been—were, to DeLong’s eyes, pursuing “doctrines of orthodoxy and austerity,” with an “insistence on pure laissez-faire, that the government should simply leave the economy alone.”

We’re given many florid phrases about the horrid “anarchy of the market” and how the market “failed” to provide this or that imagined good. DeLong often seems to believe that because things exist in abundance somewhere in the world, we can all have anything we desire—physical distribution, durability, or political and institutional obstacles be damned. That’s an odd thing to publish in 2022, at the tail end of skyrocketing inflation and an energy crisis that, in part, resulted from insufficiently movable energy.

Kevin Corcoran writes insightfully about spontaneous order.

{ 0 comments }

Quotation of the Day…

… is from page 381 of George Will’s 2021 book, American Happiness and Discontents: The Unruly Torrent, 2008-2020 – a collection of many of his columns over these years; (the column from which the quotation below is drawn was originally published in the Washington Post on April 25th, 2018) (original emphasis):

So, the [United States Holocaust Memorial] museum presents human nature’s noblest as well as vilest manifestations. It has received 43 million visitors, 90 percent non-Jewish, many of whom have had opportunities to talk to survivors, such as Fanny Aizenberg, who in her 102nd year still comes most Sundays. Located just off the Mall, one of the world’s most pleasant urban spaces and the epicenter of American politics, the museum inflicts an assaultive, excruciating knowing: Nothing – nothing – is unthinkable, and political institutions by themselves provide no permanent safety from barbarism, which permanently lurks beneath civilization’s thin, brittle crust.

{ 0 comments }

Protectionists’ Cheap Tricks

In my latest column for AIER I expose three cheap tricks loved by protectionists. Two slices:

The economic and moral case for free trade is rock solid. But as even Adam Smith conceded, because reality is a cauldron of complexity and nuance, there are a tiny handful of theoretically coherent, if mostly practically irrelevant, exceptions to this case. In debates over trade, protectionists relatively seldom use these exceptions (save for their ever-present and tendentious invocations of the need to ensure national security). Instead, protectionists rely with distressing frequency on intellectual cheap tricks. Cheap tricks, fortunately, are easily exposed as such.

…..

A common theme sounded by protectionists — and, today, especially by Donald Trump and others on the political right — is that free-trade policy in America is a gift given to foreigners. And this gift, we are told, is one that Americans can no longer afford. “It’s too bad that high tariffs in the US deny foreigners the benefits they’d get from open access to our rich market,” the story goes “but we must put America first! It’s unpatriotic to deny economic advances to Americans simply to help non-Americans.”

Those who tell this story would have you believe that free traders from Adam Smith forward are “cosmopolitan elites,” who are convinced that the benefits that poor nations gain from trading freely with rich nations outweigh the resulting harm that this trade inflicts on rich nations. Using a crude utilitarian calculus that ignores the value of people’s rootedness in their nations, locales, and familiar ways of life, these elites (the protectionist story goes) then smugly conclude that free trade is justified.

If this take on reality were accurate, the US government’s retreat from free trade would indeed both enrich the great majority of ordinary Americans and be ethically defensible. But this take isn’t accurate; it’s another cheap trick.

The principal case for a policy of free trade has never been one of raising the living standards of poor-country citizens by lowering the living standards of rich-country citizens. While it’s true that free traders recognize that ordinary people in poor countries gain from free trade, it’s emphatically untrue that free traders think that these gains come at the expense of ordinary people in rich countries. From the start, the case for a policy of free trade has focused on the gains that such trade promises to ordinary people in the home country, be it rich or poor.

Gains from trade are mutual, a reality that isn’t changed one iota by imposing a political boundary between the traders. Protectionism therefore strips both foreigners and Americans of these gains. It follows that free trade in America should be embraced by anyone who truly wishes to “put America first!” — indeed, also by anyone who admits to caring only about Americans and not a hoot about non-Americans.

To truly “put America First” requires eliminating all protectionist obstructions on the peaceful commercial choices of American citizens. Ordinary Americans should ask protectionists such as Donald Trump and Josh Hawley just how America is put ‘first’ by US government trade barriers that constrict ordinary Americans’ freedom to spend their incomes as they choose.

{ 0 comments }

Some Links

Wall Street Journal columnist William McGurn applauds the work of Samuel Gregg, who does indeed stand athwart the populist economic tide. Three slices:

These days it isn’t only the Democratic left that has harsh words for the free market. The Republican right has soured on it too. From Donald Trump’s across-the-board tariffs to Marco Rubio’s industrial policy, up goes the cry: Reaganomics is dead!

This is why the Bradley Foundation’s decision to award Samuel Gregg its annual prize is so counterrevolutionary. An Australian by birth and American by choice, Mr. Gregg is an Oxford-educated scholar at the American Institute for Economic Research. In articles, books and debates he makes the case that the invisible hand not only delivers better results than the populist alternatives, it’s also superior morally. On Tuesday night in Washington, he will be honored at a gala emceed by the Journal’s Kim Strassel.

“Popular understanding of capitalism today is driven by mythological narratives,” Mr. Gregg says. “Capitalism’s defenders also have to address the narratives.” One thing these narratives often miss is something economists from Adam Smith to F.A. Hayek acknowledged: The free market depends on virtues it rewards but can’t create itself.

…..

Feeding the Republican cry that free-market policies are passé is the idea that American workers today are worse off than they were before. Certainly many Americans are struggling in the Biden economy. But the idea that the market is to blame for their problems or that working class Americans have been left behind isn’t supported by the evidence.

“Blue-collar people today are economically much better off than they were in, say, the 1950s or 1970s,” Mr. Gregg says. “Their inflation-adjusted average overall income and benefits are considerably higher, their houses are bigger, and they have access to labor-saving technologies their grandparents couldn’t even envisage.”

“The paradox of markets,” Mr. Gregg adds, “is that people pursuing their rational self-interest unintentionally produce many benefits for others, while dirigiste policies intended to help people often hurt them. Minimum wages, to take one example, seek to help the poor but price them out of labor markets, often robbing them of entry-points into the workforce.”

…..

“Markets produce the growth that gets us out of poverty,” Mr. Gregg says. “But they also encourage virtues that make us better people while simultaneously working with, rather than against, human nature. All these things make markets morally superior to all the alternatives.”

GMU Econ alum Paul Mueller decries the “Progressive groupthink” that motivated Nobel-laureate economist Esther Duflo’s to say that industrialized countries owe a debt, due to climate change, to the global south. A slice:

And I am not commenting on her published economic work, some of which is no doubt decent. Instead, I want to highlight how outrageously naïve global elites, in this case within the economics profession, have become. There are three major examples of Progressive groupthink in this relatively short interview.

Example 1 – People advance the public good by paying taxes

I think we need to rely on taxation because that is the way in which traditionally we ensure that everyone in the economy, private companies and individuals, contributes to the public good.

Setting aside the dubious claim that all or even most government spending advances the “public good,” what a narrow view of the world!

Does this mean that farmers or doctors or mechanics only contribute to the public good when they pay taxes? The question (should) answer itself! This reasoning suggests that her taxes contribute to the public good, not her research. But perhaps if her work is funded by tax dollars…

[DBx: The above-quoted statement by Duflo is breathtakingly naive. That an economist would utter it is depressing; that an economist with a Nobel Prize to her name utters it is shocking. I do indeed weep for my profession and discipline.]

The Wall Street Journal‘s Editorial Board is justly critical of Biden’s commencement address to Morehouse graduates. A slice:

The polls say President Biden has lost support among black Americans, and the White House appears to have settled on a strategy to win them back: spread more racial division. That’s the main message from the President’s dishonorable commencement address Sunday at storied Morehouse College in Atlanta.

Also critical of Biden’s speech at Morehouse is Noah Rothman. A slice:

The bleakness of life in modern America is unrelenting, as the president explained. “Today in Georgia,” Biden continued, “they won’t allow water to be available to you while you wait in line to vote in an election. What in the hell is that all about?” Once again, Biden and his spectators should take heart — their dour outlook on the state of the nation is fueled by misapprehensions.

Georgia election law does not prohibit voters from consuming whatever they like while waiting to vote, and it doesn’t prohibit service providers from doing business with prospective voters. What it does do is block electioneering from within 150 feet of a polling place or 25 feet from voters queueing up at a polling place. Biden must be aware of this elementary distinction by now; he’s retailed this false attack on Georgia’s election laws for years now. We must assume the truth would inconvenience the president in his effort to dispirit Morehouse’s graduating class.

The dirigiste nanny state in California continues to spread its tentacles.

GMU Econ alum Jon Murphy pulls back the false mask often worn by protectionists. A slice:

National defense is a common justification for protectionist tariffs, and it has been driven to absurd extremes: clothespins, sugar, and baby food have all been described as vital to national defense and subject to tariffs.

In a particularly goofy example, Senator Rick Scott of Florida has called for a ban on Chinese-grown garlic on the grounds it threatens national security.  Now, perhaps if we were a nation of vampires, this claim would make sense.  But it’s hard to see how garlic, even garlic that is potentially tainted, is a threat to national security.  Scott argues that the garlic poses a potential health threat, but that is not the same as a national security threat.

Here’s Alberto Mingardi on “the limitations of AI.”

{ 0 comments }

Quotation of the Day…

… is from page 402 of the 2016 second edition of Thomas Sowell’s important volume Wealth, Poverty and Politics:

Because the redistributionists’ argument is presented as a moral imperative for an affluent society to see that everyone has “basic necessities” – however defined – their proposal often escapes empirical tests of what such policies actually produce, compared to what is produced by policies based on the thesis that “challenging and response” spurs human achievement. The many examples of social degeneration in the wake of the all-encompassing welfare state, in both England and America, might have painfully sobering implications, if so many advocates of the welfare state were not still ignoring painful social consequences, while basking in the glow of a sense of moral superiority.

{ 0 comments }

Deficient Reporting

Here’s a letter to the Wall Street Journal:

Editor:

After reading Andrew Duehren’s latest piece (“Tariffs Push Up Costs. But Not Always Inflation,” May 19), I plead with you, America’s preeminent financial newspaper, to stop reporting the U.S. “goods deficit.” First of all, this concept has no more economic meaning than would, say, a “things-colored-blue deficit.” There is simply nothing economically special about tangible outputs; a dollar’s worth of tangible outputs has exactly the same value as does a dollar’s worth of intangible outputs – no more and no less.

Second, in the U.S., as in all advanced economies, most GDP is produced by the service sector – specifically, more than three quarters of U.S. GDP is service-sector output. There is thus every reason to expect that we Americans will consistently import more goods than we export and export more services than we import. Reporting, as you do, America’s “goods deficit” creates the false impression that something is amiss on the trade front. And every such impression is seized upon by protectionists to peddle their economic voodoo to voters.

Donald J. Boudreaux
Professor of Economics
and
Martha and Nelson Getchell Chair for the Study of Free Market Capitalism at the Mercatus Center
George Mason University
Fairfax, VA 22030

{ 0 comments }

Some Links

Bruce Yandle warns of a “bootleggers and Baptists” coalition to regulate AI. A slice:

In May 2023, OpenAI founder Sam Altman testified before the Senate Judiciary Committee about ChatGPT. Altman demonstrated how his company’s tool could massively reduce the cost of retrieving, processing, conveying, and perhaps even modifying the collective knowledge of mankind as stored in computer memories worldwide. A user with no special equipment or access can request a research report, story, poem, or visual presentation and receive in a matter of seconds a written response.

Because of ChatGPT’s seemingly vast powers, Altman called for government regulation to “mitigate the risks of increasingly powerful AI systems” and recommended that U.S. or global leaders form an agency that would license AI systems and have the authority to “take that license away and ensure compliance with safety standards.” Major AI players around the world quickly roared approval of Altman’s “I want to be regulated” clarion call.

Welcome to the brave new world of AI and cozy crony capitalism, where industry players, interest groups, and government agents meet continuously to monitor and manage investor-owned firms.

The Wall Street Journal‘s Editorial Board is no fan of the United ‘Auto’ Workers. A slice:

Still, it’s apparent that many workers aren’t interested in what the union is selling, which is less about job security than progressive priorities that extend well past the workplace. Mr. Fain presents himself as the vanguard of left-wing politics, as when he denounced Israel’s effort to destroy Hamas in Gaza. The UAW “has been calling for a ceasefire for six months,” he said recently. Why should line workers in Tuscaloosa pay dues for that?

Unions keep losing labor-market share, and official figures show the downward slide hasn’t stopped. Last year 10% of workers were union members, down from 10.1% in 2022. In the private economy, the rate was unchanged at 6%. But among public workers it fell to 32.5%, from 33.1%. Such annual changes might look small, but that’s how erosion works, a little at a time. In 2000 the private workforce was 9% unionized, and for public employees it was 36.9%.

Megan McArdle: “Women are having fewer babies. That’s bad news for retirees.” A slice:

That base reality is often obscured by the terms of the debate — by the arguments over the solvency of the trust funds, the size of cost-of-living adjustments, the merits of Social Security vs. traditional employer pensions vs. (comparatively) newfangled 401(k)s. But if you drill down to fundamentals, all retirement plans represent the same thing: a legal claim on the output of some future worker. Fewer workers per retiree means less output to claim — and more bitter political fights between workers and retirees.

Pierre Lemieux pushes back against the today’s ghosts of J.K. Galbraith and Vance Packard.

Walter Olson shares the good news of the 4th Circuit ruling that federal-tax exemption does not constitute federal financial assistance.

Randy Holcombe reports that the Fed won’t meet its inflation target this year.

{ 0 comments }

Quotation of the Day…

… is from page 44 of Northwestern University economist Joseph Ferrie’s excellent 2011 paper “A Historical Perspective on High-Skilled Immigrants to the United States, 1820-1920,” which is Chapter 1 of High-Skilled Immigration in a Global Labor Market (Barry R. Chiswick, Ed., 2011):

If immigration policy had been formulated by a benevolent social planner in the middle of the nineteenth century when U.S. cities were inundated with large numbers of unskilled Irish immigrants, it might have seemed reasonable to favor the immigration instead of higher-skilled workers – after all, such craft and clerical workers were the backbone of U.S. manufacturing to that point. But such a policy could have delayed by decades the adoption of new techniques made economical by the arrival of unskilled Irish immigrants.

{ 0 comments }

Some Links

Bruce Yandle remembers the late Hugh Macaulay on the centenary of Hugh’s birth. A slice:

Those of us who were his colleagues and friends celebrate his life as an economist and moral force in the lives of us all, as well as the lives of his students. Hugh remains one of the most “unforgettable characters we’ve ever met,” to paraphrase one of Reader’s Digest’s most popular series. He is also remembered as one of the profession’s staunchest defenders of markets, always ready to find fault with proposals to constrain the market process.

Tom Hazlett – the Hugh H. Macaulay Endowed Professor of Economics at Clemson University – is no fan of the TikTok ban. Two slices:

Writing in The Free Press, Rep. Michael Gallagher (R–Wisc.)—co-sponsor of the TikTok bill—claims that because the Chinese Communist Party allegedly “uses TikTok to push its propaganda and censor views,” the United States must move to block. This endorsement of the Chinese “governing system” evinces no awareness of the beauty of our own. We can combat propaganda with our free press (including The Free Press). Of greatest help is that the congressman singles out the odious views that the Chinese potentates push: on Tiananmen, Muslims, LGBTQ issues, Tibet, and elsewise.

Our federal jurists will do well to focus on Gallagher’s opening salvo versus TikTok: “A growing number of Americans rely on it for their news. Today, TikTok is the top search engine for more than half of Gen Z.” This underscores the fact that his new rules are not intended to be “content neutral.”

Rather than shouting about potential threats, TikTok’s foes should report any actual mendacities or violations of trust. Where criminal—as with illicitly appropriating users’ data—such misbehavior should be prosecuted by the authorities. Yet here the National Security mavens have often gone AWOL.

…..

The TikTok ban is Fool’s Gold. The First Amendment is pure genius. Let’s keep one of them.

Scott Lincicome is a fan of sports, but not of subsidized stadiums. Two slices:

[T]he harsh reality for even the biggest sports fan is that arena subsidies are a terrible use of finite government resources and a ridiculously egregious redistribution of wealth from regular Americans—fans and haters alike—to some of the wealthiest people and organizations on the planet.  And, to top it all off, they’re a classic case of political malpractice—local officials delivering massive rents to various cronies by promising unwitting voters the world yet delivering far fewer—but still “seen”—economic and social benefits to their communities.

…..

Maybe all this government support might be worth the costs if the subsidized facilities at issue produced even a fraction of the benefits that supporters promise, but they don’t. Instead, there are few positions on which more economists agree than the terribleness of sports arena subsidies. A 2022 paper by [J.C.] Bradbury and his same colleagues documented the consensus by summarizing more than 130 studies on the issue over the last 30 years, looking at not just the facilities’ direct pecuniary benefits but also indirect and intangible ones like “civic pride.”

David Henderson, with help from Ryan Bourne, explains that so-called “junk fees” typically serve important purposes.

Edward Glaeser, Radu Barza, César A. Hidalgo, and Martina Viarengo find that “cities are engines of opportunities.”

George Will again eviscerates the case for government control of political speech, including such speech that is funded with more money than ‘progressives’ and some conservatives deem appropriate. Two slices:

Because the Supreme Court has largely agreed that campaign finance restrictions can violate free-speech guarantees, in 2014, not a single Democratic senator opposed amending the First Amendment to empower Congress to regulate the quantity, content and timing of campaign speech. That is, speech about the composition of Congress and the rest of the government. Campaign “reforms” were harbingers of progressives’ subsequent embrace of restrictions on many forms of speech, especially but not only on campuses.

…..

As an unsuccessful candidate for her party’s nomination in 2008, and accepting her party’s nomination in 2016, Hillary Clinton wanted to “get money out of politics.” But also in 2016 she overcame her aversion to money and outspent Trump 3 to 1. The progressive aspiration is to remove private money from politics.

This would extend government’s domination of society to politics — to the debate about the composition of government. The maximum progressive aim is to remove voluntary political contributions from politics and restrict candidates to spending money that government extracts from voters by taxation. The overwhelming majority of voters — this we know — will not voluntarily pay for politics.

Every year, Americans can check a box on their tax returns, thereby giving $3 (without increasing their tax liabilities) to fund the presidential campaigns of nominees who agree not to accept other money. In 2023, only 3.35 percent of tax filers checked the box.

GMU Econ alum Dominic Pino reports on the mythical great UAW unionization wave.

Johan Norberg has good news.

{ 0 comments }

Quotation of the Day…

… is from page 19 of W. Duncan Reekie’s 1988 Managerial and Decision Economics paper titled “Consumers’ Sovereignty Revisited“; by “custom thought” – a term coined by W.H. Hutt – Reekie refers to that part of the human psyche that fears change:

The essence of a competitive economy is entrepreneurial alertness to and search for new and better ways of doing things – in short, change. Cartelization, however damaging to the community at large, removes or appears to remove the discordant change from cartel participants. Custom thought can thus be readily harnessed to oppose any threatened convulsion.

DBx: Protectionism is the effort to protect particular individuals, in their roles as producers, from having to adjust to changes in the preferences of their fellow citizens. Protectionism, thus, is a means of compelling the masses to pay for the comfort of the few.

{ 0 comments }